As we shall soon see, game theory
has a number of applications in sports. This is not all that surprising because,
after all, sports are games that have implicit costs, utilities and strategies.
In this discussion, the game theoretic underpinnings of soccer will be
considered. Likely the two most common invocations of game theory with regard
to soccer are the semifinalists’ dilemma and the decision theory of penalty
kicks.
The semifinalists’ dilemma arises
from the distribution of a finite level of stamina between the semifinal round and
final round. We assume there are four equally matched semifinalists (representative
of opposing soccer teams) A, B, C, and D. In the first round—the semifinal round—A will contest B, and C will contest D. The two prevailing teams from the semifinals will advance to the
final round, in which both players will vie for the championship title. The two
losers from the semifinal round will return in the final round to compete for
third place. The players’ payoffs will be given by the results of the
tournament. Let’s denote these different payoffs i , j, k, and l, such
that i < j < k < l. This implies that l represents the payoff of the winning player,
while i represents the loser’s
payoff.
Figure 1. How do you distribute stamina in the Soccer World Cup?
We can assume the outcome of a game
can be modeled by a probability density function, which gives a player’s
probability as an increasing function of stamina investment. This suggests that
a player’s probability of winning the semifinal game, p, depends on the amount of stamina he is willing to expend.
Because the level of stamina is assumed to be finite, the player has a
probability 1-p of winning in the
final round.
Recall that we stipulated that our
players A, B, C, and D
were evenly matched and had equal amounts of stamina. Each player’s strategy—and
resulting payoff—will depend on how much stamina he is willing to expend in the
semifinal round. Therein lies the dilemma; how much stamina should be spent in
the semifinal round? Is it better for a player to fully exert himself ensuring
a victory in the semifinal, or is it better to reserve some stamina for the
subsequent championship round?
The answer of course depends on the
value of i, j, k, l. There are three possible Nash equilibria.
First, any pure strategy (i.e. exert or reserve) will be a Nash equilibrium
when the winner receives a much greater payoff than the other players. Second, if first and second place have much
higher payoffs than third or fourth place, and the payoffs are not
significantly different, then the only Nash equilibrium is such that all
players employ a pure strategy and expend all of their stamina in the semifinal
round. Third, if the payoff for last place is significantly less than any other
finish, a Nash equilibrium is formed when all players adopt a mixed strategy
whereby each player uses all or none of his stamina in the semifinal game. In
essence, the players’ strategies will depend on their value of the payoffs for
each finish in the tournament.
My
explanation here is a little ambiguous. If you are curious about the onerous
math behind these generalizations, check out this article.
Now,
let’s turn our attention to the decision theory behind penalty kicks. Penalty
kicks are awarded to the team whose opponent has committed a foul. In a penalty
kick, a kicker attempts to score on the opponent’s goal, defended only by the
goalkeeper. The goalkeeper must stand on the goal line until the ball has
been kicked, and then he must make a dive left or right to try and block the
incoming ball.
For the
sake of a game theoretic analysis of penalty kicks, we must make the following
assumptions:
- The kicker kicks precisely at the same time the goalie dives. This isn’t an entirely unreasonable assumption, as it takes an average of 0.3 seconds for the ball to reach the goal. So the goalie definitely doesn’t have time to deliberate which way he needs to dive.
- The kicker and goalie employ mixed strategies. That is, the kicker may kick to the left or the right of the goal with probabilities p and 1-p, and the goalie may dive left or right with probabilities q and 1-q.
- If the kicker kicks the ball in the same direction that the goalie dives, the ball will be successfully blocked. If the kicker kicks the ball in the opposite direction that the goalie dives, the kicker will successfully score a goal.
This model closely resembles the
game of matching pennies. In matching pennies, two competitors, A and B, simultaneously display pennies. If the pennies do not match (heads,
tails), then player A collects one
dollar from player B. On the other
hand, if the pennies match ((heads, heads) or (tails, tails)) then player B receives one dollar from player A. The payoff matrix is as follows:
Figure 2. A payoff matrix for the matching pennies game.
The example of matching pennies can
be modified to model penalty kicks. If the direction of the goalie’s dive "matches" the direction of the kick, then he successfully defends the goal and both players receive a payoff of zero; the score remains the same. However, if the
direction of the goalie’s dive does not match the direction of the kick, he
misses the ball and receives a payoff of -1, and the kicker scores a payoff of
1. The results are summarized in the payoff matrix below.
Figure 3. A payoff matrix for the penalty kick.
No
doubt, this model is flawed. Here, we assume there’s a 50/50 chance that a
player will choose one direction over another. In truth, there is a much higher
probability that a right-footed player will kick the ball left; a left-footed
player is also more likely to kick the ball right (and surely ambipedal soccer
players are few and far between). We can also presume that goalies don’t just dive
willy-nilly. Professional goalies probably make a point of checking players’
footedness. The kicker’s approach to the ball is also pretty telling. If he is
right-footed, he would actually have to approach the ball on an arc and angle
his body away from the goal to make a right shot.
Goalie be like…
Figure 4. Goalies aren't quite as clueless as our model makes them out to be.
Well, that’s all folks. Looking
forward to our discussion of game theory in sports!
References:
Baek, Seung Ki, Seung-Woo Son, and Jeong Hyeong-Chai. "Nash
Equilibrium and Evolutionary Dynamics in Semifinalists' Dilemma." American
Physical Society, 30 Apr. 2015. Web. 15 Nov. 2015.
Grant, Andrew. "Here's What Game Theory Says about How to Win
in Semifinals." Science News. N.p., 22 May 2015. Web. 15 Nov.
2015.
Harford, Tim. "What Economics Teaches about Penalty
Kicks." Slate. N.p., 24 June 2006. Web. 15 Nov. 2015.
Spaniel, William. "The Game Theory of Soccer Penalty
Kicks." William Spaniel. N.p., 12 June 2014. Web. 15 Nov. 2015.
Great post! I wonder if we can actually come up with a reasonable model using a little bit of the probability you mentioned at the end. For instance, let's just pretend there are 4 options for where the ball is going to be aimed (top left, top right, bottom left, bottom right) and a given kicker has some probabilities (p1, p2, p3, p4) of making each of these respective shots. And let's just say the goalie will block 100% effectively IF (s)he chooses to dive in the correct one of the 4 directions. This augments the overly simplified model by taking the "footedness" into account, as you mentioned. What does the payoff matrix look like now? E.g. what if a kicker makes 100% of his top left kicks, 80% of his bottom left kicks, but only 10% of his top right and bottom right kicks? What is the Nash Equilibrium here?
ReplyDeleteThis question is for everyone, by the way. Let's discuss it tomorrow. :)
The 50/50 left-right model is pretty boring, so I'm glad we're spicing things up. If anybody's curious check out this video: https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=OTs5JX6Tut4
DeleteHi Jesse, great presentation yesterday. I thought I'd add a little about penalty kicks and how awful / awesome they are to watch. Most players will have two locations that they choose to shoot at depending on the day, for example one player will either shoot hard to the top left corner, or to curl it into the bottom right corner. The most common ways for goalies to learn and stop these kicks is to look at the takers career percentages on where he shoots, and then since he has essentially narrowed it down to two spots to dive for, look for clues in the shooter's run up. The other option which is fairly common is to shoot down the middle with a power shot or a chip, which is rather cheeky. Figured I'd attach a link if anyone wants to check out some down the middle chips that have and haven't come off... (the penalty chip is called a panenka by the way)
ReplyDeletehttps://www.youtube.com/watch?v=DqJpnCmIvnA
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=hzDZ1U33MjU
Hey guys! At the end of my presentation, we were all wondering about the Mixed Startegy Nash Equilibrium for penalty kicks. If you're interested here's an article that sheds some light on subject.
ReplyDeletehttps://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/20964/1/MPRA_paper_20964.pdf